Merger Mania

Henry C.k. Liu hliu at mindspring.com
Sun Dec 6 18:20:20 PST 1998


There are many aspects of the current merger mania that are different than that of a century ago when Rockefeller gained control of oil, Carnegie of steel and Frick of railroads. The arena then was the domestic market, and the rationale was to impose order and efficiency on emerging industries already in the process of consolidation. It was Rockefeller, an accountant by profession, who created the business "trust" as a vehicle to control a large number (40) of different corporations that he had acquired. The term later came to mean in common usage a large combine with monopolistic powers. Throughout the 1880s, public opinion was increasingly concerned with the growth of monopolies, the most vocal and bitter opponents of which being small entrepreneurs and businesses. There were concerns also with the big trusts and corporate giants controlled by "holding companies" created overnight through mergers. The mood then was populist, anti-bigness in business but not in government. The fear of unfair monopoly was greater than the fear of regulation. A number of states passed laws prohibiting trusts and other forms of corporate combination, but they were ineffective because some states, notably Delaware and New Jersey, continued to grant corporate charters with few monopolistic restrictions. Liberal reformers then turned to Federal legislation as the obvious solution. As with the Interstate Commerce Act of 1887 which sought unsuccessfully to prohibit railroad rebates, long and short haul rate differentials and other forms of pricing discrimination, (the Supreme Court in 1897 nullified the ICC's authority to set rates), Congress did not feel that anti-trust legislation was desirable or practicable. Nevertheless, yielding to public sentiment, Congress passed the loosely worded Sherman Anti-Trust Act by a near unanimous vote in 1890, in a crude attempt to deal with the problem by declaring illegal, attempts to monopolize markets, or combine corporations or conspire in restraint of trade among the several states, or with foreign countries. But neither the Justice Department nor the courts showed much interest in compliance. Historians have categorized 4 sequential phases in the development of capitalism: agricultural capitalism, mercantile capitalism, industrial capitalism and finance capitalism. The 1890s marked the rise of investment banking in America and the beginning of finance capitalism, symbolized by the House of Morgan whose higher standard of financial integrity put an end to buccaneering corporate raiders like Jay Gould who made money by arranging mergers, watering stocks and then selling the diluted company shares at high profit to an unknowing public. Labor solidarity, lacking a strong tradition due to the American heritage of individualism, was impeded further by racial, ethnic, linguistic and religious differences and by the prejudices harbored by native-born American workers against blacks and new immigrants. In 1865, William H. Sylvis organized the National Labor Union which claimed a membership of 600,000 by 1868, but disbanded within 4 years due external pressure and internal dispute over the correctness of pushing for political reforms without sufficient sense for realism. A year later, in 1869, Uriah Stephens organized the Knights of Labor (KOL), with agrarian idealism and Jacksonian individualism under the slogan: "Every man his own master and employer". Membership was universal, excluding only lawyers, bankers, stockbrokers, liquor dealers, and professional gamblers. It sought to achieve its goal by organizing cooperatives and through legislation rather than conflict with the employing class. Despite being buoyant by a period of rising labor militancy, with a member up to 700,000 by 1886 under the leadership of Terence Powderly, the KOL floundered by failing to support strikes, in preference for producer's cooperatives that eventually failed as a result of mismanagement or business hostility. The American Federation of Labor (AFL) was organized in 1881 under the leadership of Samuel Gompers, with salaried professional officials, strict discipline, regular dues and strike funds and insurance. The Sherman Act was at times used by the court to issue injunctions against strikes based on a "restraint of trade" argument. The Fourteenth Amendment was used to declare labor laws unconstitutional until the 1935 Wagner Act which legalized the right to collective bargaining. Eugene Debs, the Railway Union leader, emerged from a 6-month prison term for contempt of court, became the leader of the Socialist Party, but received little labor support even for its mild program of peaceful and democratic methods. The Industrial Workers of the World (IWW) was formed in 1893 with one million members, known as "Wobblies", organized by William D. Haywood, a mine workers leader. It offered a radical program calling for the revolutionary overthrow of the capitalistic system. It was crushed during the wave of anti radical hysteria following WWI. Theodore Roosevelt, defender of the principle of government supremacy over business, and charismatic politician of the Progressive Movement, began his trust-busting campaign in 1902, in preparation for his reelection in 1904. The campaign created great popular enthusiasm and matching violent reaction from corporate magnates, but it gave TR a plurality of 2.5 million votes in the 1904 election. Yet in his second term, TR's anti-trust accomplishments were less than impressive. While the trusts were compelled by court decisions to dissolve into component entities, these entities could not be transformed to different ownership, or be compelled to compete with each other. The new components in effect divided up the national market into regional sections with no real competition. The courts further stipulated that only court interpreted "undue" and "unreasonable" restraint of trade was prohibited by the Sherman Act. TR was supported by big business which understood that he was in truth its savior by forcing business to conform to a high standard in order to prevent the growth of revolutionary sentiments. TR himself declared that "we draw the line against misconduct, not against wealth". Progressive politics was dominated by two foci: fight against political corruption of bosses and machines and opposition to monopolies and their exploitation of farmers and workers. It was not a revolutionary movement but a reaffirmation of traditional American ideals of democracy , individual freedom, the rule of law and the protection of private property. Progressives reject class struggle and rely on ethical, humanitarian and religious values. American attitude toward the proper role of government shifted several times throughout its history. Progressives accept the necessity for government to assume broader regulatory responsibilities and economic functions, along Hamiltonian lines. With the growth of big business, the emergence of a large working class, and the deterioration of the economic position of farmers, there was a shift between Jeffersonian laissez faire and Hamiltonian big government positions, with conservatives assuming the former and liberals the latter. Among progressives, there were also two attitudes toward monopolies. One, represented by T. Roosevelt, argued that bigness was an inevitable economic trend and that government regulation over their excess was necessary, while the other, represented by Woodrow Wilson, advocated the prohibition of monopolies, protection of small businesses, and preserving competition. Robert Marion LaFollete of Wisconsin, was responsible for introducing social science as the argument for reform, by bringing academic experts into policy marking in government. By 1929, monopolistic trends had shifted towards oligopoly in which a few corporations controlled the market by cooperating in maintaining prices through a price leader, while they competed through improvement in quality and services and through advertising. Many causes had been identified for the crash of 1929 and the subsequent economic collapse. Aside from the speculative bubble, one fundamental factor was that wages were rising much slower than productivity. Thus an overcapcity in production inevitably resulted. Another factor was the uneven distribution of income that prevented a general rise of consumer purchasing power amid a superficial boom limited to only a small segment of the population. This deficiency of purchasing power was masked by the growth of debt, made possible with the introduction of installment financing which led to a sever credit crunch. The imbalance of a high return on capital had a direct bearing in keeping income low and purchasing power deficient in relation to the growth of savings available for new investment. Another factor was the rise in foreign investment in the U.S. which had shifted from a debtor nation prior to WWI to a creditor nation in 1929. America was financing its export by lending foreign buyers the money. The lack of effective government supervision allowed Wall Street bankers to collect profitable commissions by risking the savings American citizens entrusted to them in unsound investments overseas. Price fixing by major corporations deprived the economy of the necessary flexibility and capacity for quick adjustment . Instead of cutting prices to stimulate consumption and maintaining production, the corporations maintained prices and cut employment., thus further depressing consumer demand for their products. The emphasis of the economy toward capital goods also made the recovery agonizingly slow because capital goods tended to be the last sector to rebound. The New Deal was a continuation of the Progressive Movement. Its main purpose was to save capitalism by bringing about recovery. It sought through government public works programs and deficit financing to stop the process of deflation and unemploymant. In 1935, a group of militant union leaders, including John L. Lewis of the United Mine Workers, Sidlney Hillman of the amalgamated Clothing workers and Dvid Dubinsky of the International Ladies Garment Workers, noting the failure of the AFL to respond to the demand for industrial unionism, broke away and set up a Committee for industrial ORganization (CIO). Under the leadership of Lewis, CIO expanded reapidly and won notable successes in steel and automobiles. By 1940, total union membership reached 9 million, although still only 25% of the work force, but unionis was strongly entrenched in all basic industries. The New Deal failed in its primary objective of full employment through revival of production. There was no attempt to make structural changes in the pownership and control of basic economic enterprises. In fact, American corporations were bigger and more concentrated in 1940 than in 1929. It did provide an extensive social safety net program and inmcrease government responsibility in the regulation of commerce. After WWII, the global economy was distorted by the geopolitics of the Cold War. The militarization of the peace throughout the Cold War hid the classic relationship between low wages and over capacity, because military expenditures soaked up the excess capital. Reagan economics and foreign policy essentially spent the Soviet Union into bankruptcy and piled up historic levels of debt for the U.S., deregualted the U.S. economy at the same time decimated unionism in American industry. Now, less than a decade after the fall of the Berlin Wall, the classic factors that causes depressions: low wages and high returns on capital, are once again threatening the world's economies. The only thing different this time is that America now is the world's biggest debtor nation, but acts as if she is still the world's biggest creditor nation, with the financial resources to bail out a world mired in deep financial crisis. It is interesting to note that Allan Greenspan, in his recent testimony on monopolies before Congress, argued: that government is inept at determining in advance those mergers that would create competitive problems and the it would be wiser to wait and see. To this old laissez faire line, two new arguments are added: that mergers are necessary for survival in a global economy and the technological imperative mandates them. But the current mergers in manufacturing (Daimler/Chrysler), finance Citibank/Traveller, Deutch Bank/Bankers Trust), energy (Mobil/Exxon), etc. are all focus on price stability through cost cutting, mainly through massive worker reduction, thus exacerbating the over capacity and under consumption -problem that will again bring the global economy crashing down. My suggestion for a solution to the current financial/economic crisis is simple: a massive across the board increase in wages worldwide, 25% annually for LDCs and 10% for MDCs, until consumption soaks up the world's overcapacity in production. As for mergers, they should be allowed only if they do not lead to layoff of workers and if they are accompanied by increased wages.

Henry C.K. Liu

Rakesh Bhandari wrote:


> Having never read a textbook like Copeland and Weston's Finacial Theory and
> Corporate Policy, I would ask Henry and others about the significance of
> these mergers being mostly stock, not cash, deals;

It is an expedient strategy to skirt the current credit crunch.


> also are mergers
> concentrated today in certain kinds of industries, not others?

It is dictated by which indusry has the higest degree of excess capacity and under the most severe deflationary pressure.


> Which
> industries are most concentrated in the US; does such a pattern hold in
> other countries? Will the main effect of mergers be to give monopoly power
> to national capital at home and thereby the ability to secure additional
> surplus value in circulation while positioning these monopolies to better
> compete on the global market in which each can undersell the other as each
> can sells at marginal costs for the sole purpose of destroying
> international rivals having made superprofits in production and circulation
> at home?

Merger are not designed to increase competition, rather they aim to stabilized prices with increased efficientcy through labor cost reduction.


> What percentage of profits do these monopolies make at home? And ,
> following Brenner, what are the implications of these mergers for the
> nature of competition on the world market?

I have never read the authors you named, nor do I have any desire to.

Henry



More information about the lbo-talk mailing list