statistical fallacy of aging population?

Rosser Jr, John Barkley rosserjb at jmu.edu
Sat Nov 28 10:20:37 PST 1998


Michael Pollak,

Sorry, but you are simply wrong. The classic pattern of the demographic transition is for the death rate to drop first, thus increasing the numbers of the elderly, and then for the birth rate to drop later. That has held true in pretty much every nation in the world. I am not aware of any exceptions to that generalization (although there are some where the birth rate has yet to decline, and others where the death rate has gone back up again either due to wars or AIDS epidemics). Barkley Rosser On Sat, 28 Nov 1998 07:51:58 -0500 (EST) Michael Pollak <mpollak at panix.com> wrote:


> On Fri, 27 Nov 1998, Henry C.K. Liu wrote:
>
> > The factors your calculation neglected are, over time:
> > 1) life expectancy lengthens, from say 68 to 87.
> > 2) retirement age lowers, from 70 to 60
> > 3) dependent age lengthens, from 18 to 22
> > 3) ratio of parents to children drops, from 2.5 to 1.5
> >
> > It all adds to to less workers for more dependents for the intermediate
> > cycle. In the long run, you are right.
>
> It seems to me it should be the opposite. Declining birth rate preceded
> the aging population in the US, no? So it seems we should have lost more
> young dependents sooner than we gained elderly ones. And isn't this
> generally true, that a rise in prosperity leads to a fall in the birth
> rate before it leads to a rise in life expectancy? Of course, once you
> reach Zero Population Growth, all the rise is in the old people. Which
> would seem to suggest the opposite, that in the long run I'm wrong, but in
> the short run I'm right. But in the really long run, we're just returning
> to an earlier state of affairs, and all this scare talk about how can we
> manage to support all these dependents is just tosh when you compare it to
> how many dependents workers with huge families were supporting in the 19C,
> and at a much lower general standard of living. Which is my main point.
> If I'm right.
>
> By the way, when you broke out those individual factors, does that mean
> you know how they each feed into the overall age distribution? And is
> that where you derive this short run/long run idea? Is so, please supply
> the details. I'd love to follow you on this point. I'd love to know how
> many children per family equalled how many years per old person in the
> total ratio of dependents.
>
> > But the demographic cycle is
> > changing faster than the ecconomic cycle structurally, so the social
> > norms regarding taxes, savings rate and reitement schemes, etc., are
> > going to be out of phase with the changing social pattern.
>
> Well it's true that parents seem to spend as much on a single child today
> as parents spent a generation ago on 3, as if they were dividing the same
> pot among fewer kids. And arguably that soaks up the surplus. But that's
> social norms changing too quickly rather than too slowly, no?
>
> Michael
> __________________________________________________________________________
> Michael Pollak................New York City..............mpollak at panix.com
>
> "Some one has observed that Providence is always on the side of the big
> dividends," remarked Reginald.
>
> The Duchess ate her anchovy in a shocked manner, she was sufficiently
> old-fashioned to dislike irreverence towards dividends.
>
> "Reginald at the Carlton" (1904) by Saki
> __________________________________________________________________________
>

-- Rosser Jr, John Barkley rosserjb at jmu.edu



More information about the lbo-talk mailing list