Greenspan

Henry C.K. Liu hliu at mindspring.com
Fri Feb 19 12:33:53 PST 1999


Federal Reserve Board

Testimony of Chairman Alan Greenspan

The crisis in emerging market economies

Before the Committee on the Budget, U.S. Senate

September 23, 1998

The crisis in emerging market economies that began in Thailand a little over a

year ago, spread to other economies in East Asia and Russia, and has most

recently been pressuring a number of economies in Latin America. There is little

evidence to suggest that the contagion has subsided.

Moreover, the declines in Asian export markets only added to the difficulties in

Japan, which was struggling with a preexisting set of corrosive banking problems.

Those difficulties have contributed to that economy's most protracted recession in

the postwar era.

As I indicated several weeks ago to a university audience, it is just not credible

that the United States, or for that matter Europe, can remain an oasis of

prosperity unaffected by a world that is experiencing greatly increased stress.

With few signs that the financial crisis that started in Asia last year has subsided,

or is about to do so, policymakers around the world have to be especially

sensitive to the deepening signs of global distress, which can impact their own

economies.

In emerging markets, after about six months of relative stability, heightened

perceptions of credit risk erupted in mid-August when Russia, which seemed to

have been making progress toward greater stability, fell into renewed crisis.

Russia is not large in the world's trade accounts or critical to the stability of the

international financial system. Nevertheless, the severity of its crisis and the

authorities' inability to contain it reflected a significant jump of contagion out of

East Asia, which, until then, had been assumed to have gone into remission.

The shock drove yields on dollar-denominated debt securities of emerging market

economies sharply higher across the globe, engulfing economies that are as

radically different as Korea, Brazil, Poland, South Africa, and China. To be sure,

some yields have increased only one to two percentage points, while others have

risen ten points or more. But all these economies have experienced stress. The

flight to safety has significantly augmented the demand for U.S. Treasury

securities, whose yields have declined in tandem with the increases in yields on

most dollar-denominated sovereign debt in international bond markets.

In recent weeks, that shift internationally has also been accompanied by a rising

concern for risk in the United States, presumably reflecting the fear that the

contagion would adversely affect our economy.

When I testified before the Congress in July, I noted that some of the effects of

the international crisis had actually been positive for the U.S. financial markets

and economy, for example, by lowering long-term interest rates paid by our

households and businesses. However, the most recent more virulent phase of the

crisis has infected our markets as well. Concerns about business profits and a

general pulling back from risk-taking in the midst of great uncertainty around the

globe have driven down stock prices and pushed up rates on the bonds of

lower-rated borrowers. Flows of funds through financial markets have been

disrupted, at least temporarily. Issuance of equity, and of bonds by lower-rated

corporations, has come virtually to a halt; even investment-grade companies have

cut back substantially on their borrowing in capital markets. Banks also are

reportedly becoming more cautious and more expensive lenders to many

companies.

There is little evidence to date, however, that foreign problems or the tightening in

financial conditions in domestic markets have produced any significant underlying

weakness in the American economy as a whole. Moreover, labor markets remain

tight and hourly compensation has continued to grow more rapidly. Nonetheless,

the increases in overall costs and the CPI have been held to modest levels by

reasonably good productivity advances, lower oil prices, and foreign competition.

However, looking forward, the restraining effects of recent developments on the

U.S. economy are likely to intensify. As I noted in congressional testimony last

week, we can already see signs of the erosion of production around the edges,

especially in manufacturing. Disappointing profits in a number of industries and

less rapid expansion of sales suggest some stretching out of capital investment

plans in the months ahead. Lower equity prices and higher financing costs should

damp household and business spending, and greater uncertainty and risk aversion

may also lead to more cautious spending behavior.

When I testified on monetary policy in July, I explained that the Federal Open

Market Committee was concerned that high--indeed rising--demand for labor

could produce cost pressures on our economy that would disrupt the ongoing

expansion. I also noted that a high real federal funds rate was a necessary offset

to expansionary conditions elsewhere in financial markets. By mid-August the

Committee believed that disruptions abroad and more cautious behavior by

investors at home meant that the risks to the expansion had become evenly

balanced. Since then, deteriorating foreign economies and their spillover to

domestic markets have increased the possibility that the slowdown in the growth

of the American economy will be more than sufficient to hold inflation in check.

As I have indicated in earlier presentations, the dramatic advances in computer

and telecommunications technologies over the last decade have fostered a marked

increase in the degree of sophistication of financial products. A vast new array of

debt, equity and hybrid instruments, as well as newly crafted derivative products

have fostered an unbundling of risks, which, in turn, has enabled investors to

optimize (as they see it) their portfolios of financial assets. This has engendered a

set of market prices and interest rates that have guided business organizations

increasingly toward producing those capital investments that offer the highest

long-term rates of return, that is, those investments that most closely align

themselves with the prospective value preferences of consumers. This process

has effectively directed scarce savings into our most potentially valuable

productive capital assets. The result, especially in the United States, where

financial innovations are most advanced, has been an evident acceleration in

productivity and standards of living, and, owing to the financial sector's increased

contribution to the process, a greater share of national income earned by it over

the past decade.

The new financial innovations, which have spread at a quickened pace, have

facilitated a rapid expansion of cross-border investment and trade, and almost

surely, as a consequence, a significant increase in standards of living for those

nations that have chosen to participate in what can appropriately be called our

new international financial system. The system is new in the sense that its

dynamics appear somewhat more accelerated relative to the international financial

structure of, say, fifteen or twenty years ago. Owing to the newer technologies,

market prices have become more sensitively tuned to subtle changes in

preferences and, hence, react to those changes far faster than in previous

generations. The system is productive of increased standards of living and more

sensitive to capital misuse. It is a system more calibrated than before to not only

reward innovation but also to discipline the mistakes of private investment or

public policy.

Thus, the crises that have emerged out of this new financial structure, while

sharing most of the characteristics of past episodes, nonetheless, appear different

in important ways. It is not yet clear whether recent crises are deeper than in the

past, or just triggered more readily.

In early 1995, I characterized the Mexican crisis as the first crisis of this new

international financial system. The crisis that started in East Asia more than a year

ago, is its second.

Since the Mexican crisis, policymakers have been engaged in an accelerated

learning process of how this new system works.

There are certain elements that are becoming evident.

The sensitivity of market responses under the new regime has been underscored

by the startling declines of exchange rates of some emerging market economies

against the dollar, and most other major currencies, of 50 percent or more in

response to what at first appeared to be relatively modest financial difficulties.

Market discipline appears far more draconian and less forgiving than twenty or

thirty years ago.

Capital, which in an earlier period may have flowed to a "merely adequate" profit

environment, owing to a lack of information or opportunity, now shifts

predominantly to those ventures or economies that appear to excel. This capital,

in times of stress, also flees more readily to securities and markets of

unquestioned quality and liquidity.

It has taken the longstanding participants in the international financial community

many decades to build sophisticated financial and legal infrastructures that buffer

shocks. Those infrastructures discourage speculative attacks against a well

entrenched currency because financial systems are robust and are able to

withstand vigorous policy responses to such attacks. For the more recent

participants in global finance, their institutions, until recently, had not been tested

against the rigors of major league pitching, to use a baseball analogy.

The situation in many emerging market economies is illustrative. Under stress,

fixed exchange rate arrangements have failed from time to time. Consequently,

domestic currency interest rates, reflecting devaluation probability premiums, are

almost always higher in emerging market economies with fixed exchange rates

than in the economy of the major currency to which the emerging economy has

chosen to peg. That currency is often the dollar.

This phenomenon, and its risky exploitation, is one important element in the

current crisis and a symptom of what has gone wrong generally. What appeared

to be a successful locking of currencies onto the dollar over a period of years in

East Asia and elsewhere, led, perhaps inevitably, to large borrowings of cheaper

dollars to lend at elevated domestic interest rates, with the intermediary pocketing

the devaluation risk premium. When the amount of unhedged dollar borrowings

finally became excessive, as was almost inevitable, the exchange rate broke.

Incidentally, it also broke in Sweden in 1992 when large borrowings of DM to

lend in krona at higher interest rates met the same fate. Such episodes are not

uncommon, suggesting that investors, even sophisticated ones, are prone to this

type of gambling.

This heightened sensitivity of exchange rates of emerging economies under stress

would be of less concern if banks and other financial institutions in those

economies were strong and well capitalized. Developed countries' banks are

highly leveraged, but subject to sufficiently effective supervision so that, in most

countries, banking problems do not escalate into international financial crises.

Most banks in emerging nations are also highly leveraged, but their supervision

often has not proved adequate to forestall failures and a general financial crisis.

The failure of some banks is highly contagious to other banks and businesses that

deal with them.

This weakness in banking supervision in emerging market economies was not a

major problem for the rest of the world prior to those economies' growing

participation in the international financial system over the past decade or so.

Exposure of an economy to short-term capital inflows, before its financial system

is sufficiently sturdy to handle a large unanticipated withdrawal, is a highly risky

venture.

It, thus, seems clear that some set of standards for participation in the new highly

sensitive international financial system is essential to its effective functioning.

There are many ways to promulgate such standards without developing an

inappropriately exclusive and restrictive club of participants.

One is far greater transparency in the way domestic finance operates and is

supervised. This is essential if investors are to make more knowledgeable

commitments and supervisors are to judge the soundness of such commitments

by their financial institutions. A better understanding of financial regimes as yet

unseasoned in the vicissitudes of our international financial system also will enable

counterparties to more appropriately evaluate the credit standing of institutions

investing in such financial systems. There is no mechanism, however, to insulate

investors from making foolish decisions, but some of the ill-advised investing of

recent years can be avoided in the future if investors, their supervisors, and

counterparties, are more appropriately forewarned.

To the extent that policymakers are unable to anticipate or evaluate the types of

complex risks that the newer financial technologies are producing, the answer, as

it always has been, is less leverage, i.e. less debt, more equity, and, hence, a

larger buffer against adversity and contagion.

I must also stress the obvious necessity of sound monetary and fiscal policies

whose absence was so often the cause of earlier international financial crises.

With increased emphasis on private international capital flows, especially

interbank flows, private misjudgments within flawed economic structures have

been the major contributors to recent problems. But inappropriate macropolicies

also have been a factor for some emerging market economies in the current crisis.

Improvements in transparency, commercial and legal structures, as well as

supervision that I, and my colleagues, have supported in recent months cannot be

implemented quickly. Such improvements and the transition to a more effective

and stable international financial system will take time. The current crisis,

accordingly, will have to be addressed with ad hoc remedies. It is essential,

however, that those remedies not conflict with a broader vision of how our new

international financial system will function as we enter the next century.

Marta Russell wrote:


> A while back there was discussion about Greenspan making some noise
> about the fact that the U.S. could not remain an "oasis" in the middle
> of the world economic mess. Does anyone have a source for that
> statement?
>
> Thanks in advance.
>
> Marta Russell



More information about the lbo-talk mailing list