Japan syndrome

Doug Henwood dhenwood at panix.com
Wed Feb 9 11:12:41 PST 2000


Date: Wed, 9 Feb 2000 13:34:24 -0500 (EST) From: Rakesh Bhandari <bhandari at phoenix.Princeton.EDU>

This is from today's NYT editorial page. Krugman a bourgeois economist here recommends inflation targetting through money creation. By 1974 Mattick had already revealed such Keynesianism to be a form of "civilized" class warfare. Quoting here from Economic Crisis and Crisis Theory, p. 147-8 which was translated in 1981:

"Inflation is a weapon in the Keynesian arsenal. Through the more rapid increase in prices relative to wages, the profit necessary for expansion grows, while the accelerated creation of money reduces the interest on the debt, which makes investment easier. The surplus value gained in this way, equal to the reduction in the value of labor power transferred from money to productive capital, permits a corresponding increase in accumulation...The real gains that inflation yields to capital are thus only another form of the devaluation of labor power, which happens in every crisis. What used to be accomplished by deflationary means is now effected by inflationary means, not by lowering wages but by raising prices--or by a combination of both. The increase in profits by means of inflation encounters definite barriers, however, as the reduction of the value of labor power has absolute limits, and even these cannot be reached because of the resistance of the workers. Moreover, the increase in total demand brings with it an increase in the demand for labor power, which in itself restricts the lowering of wages by price inflation." ____________________________________________

The Japan Syndrome

Join a Discussion on Paul Krugman

When Japan's Kansai International Airport was being planned,there was considerable uncertainty over how much the artificial island on which it sits would sink. The officials in charge chose to accept the lowest, most favorable estimate; as it turned out, the reality has been worse than even the most pessimistic estimate, and despite expensive emergency measures -- and continual assurances from those officials that everything is under control -- the island is still sinking.

It's not a bad metaphor for the story of Japanese economic policy in recent years. Japan's government keeps on insisting that its economic strategy has put the nation on the road to sustained recovery, brushing aside both the doubts of outside economists and the growing evidence that the strategy is not, in fact, working. For most of the past year this unwarranted confidence has been supported by a strange consensus on the part of investment analysts, who somehow became committed as a group to the view that Japan's economy is on the mend.

And so it came as a shock last Sunday when a senior official admitted that the Japanese economy has almost certainly been shrinking for the last two quarters, which means that by the usual definition it has slipped back into recession.

Japan has the dubious distinction of being the first major nation since the 1930's to experience a "liquidity trap," in which even cutting the interest rate all the way to zero doesn't induce enough business investment to restore full employment. The result is an economy that has been depressed since the early 90's, and that in 1998 seemed to be on the verge of a catastrophic deflationary spiral.

The government's answer has been to prop up demand with deficit spending; over the past few years Japan has been frantically building bridges to nowhere and roads it doesn't need.

In the short run this policy works: in the first half of 1999, powered by a burst of public works spending, the Japanese economy grew fairly rapidly. But deficit spending on such a scale cannot go on much longer. Japan's government is already deeply in debt (about twice as deep, relative to national income, as the U.S. was before our own budget turned around). For the policy to do more than buy a little time, the recovery must become "self-sustaining": consumers and businesses have to start spending enough to allow the government to return to fiscal responsibility without provoking a new recession.

Carping critics (like me) warned that there was no good reason to think this would happen. Sure enough, it hasn't; as the big public works projects of early 1999 have wound down, so has the economy.

What can Japan do? One answer is "reform": deregulation and a breakup of the cozy collusion that still characterizes much Japanese business could open up new investment opportunities. But this is at best a long-term answer; in the short run, by making workers feel insecure, it could actually make things worse.

The other answer is "roll the printing presses." Although the Bank of Japan has already reduced the short-term interest rate to zero, Western economists have pointed out that there are other things it can and should do: buy longer-term bonds, announce a positive target for inflation to encourage businesses to borrow. Indeed, textbook economics tells us that to adhere to conventional monetary rules in the face of a liquidity trap is not prudent; it is irresponsible. (Full disclosure: I personally have been the most visible and vociferous advocate of inflation targeting).

But the current government has actually slowed the pace of reform, and the Bank of Japan -- which only recently acquired Federal Reserve-style autonomy -- has adamantly refused to do anything unconventional. (When I was in Japan in December, I witnessed an argument between former B.O.J. officials and current officials of the Ministry of Finance.

The former declared that it would be wrong to do anything risky; the latter reminded them, to no avail, that the current policy of running up huge debts to finance public works is already very risky.)

Will the bad news make them reconsider? Don't count on it: since

Sunday's awkward admission, Japanese officials have been out in force, insisting as usual that they have everything under control.



More information about the lbo-talk mailing list