[lbo-talk] Krugman on the refutation of Bernanke crisis theory

Michael Pollak mpollak at panix.com
Mon Sep 22 22:56:04 PDT 2008


[The succinctest discussion of a liquidity trap yet.]

http://krugman.blogs.nytimes.com/2008/09/22/the-humbling-of-the-fed-wonkish/

September 22, 2008, 7:54 am

The humbling of the Fed (wonkish)

A bit off the Paulson plan topic, but not entirely ...

Not a day has gone by since this crisis began that I haven't been

thankful that Ben Bernanke is the chairman of the Fed; had events

gone a bit differently (thank you Harriet Meiers!) the post might

well have gone to some unqualified Bush loyalist.

That said, the Fed's experience in this crisis has been humbling;

getting traction has proved harder than BB himself suggested in his

pre-crisis writings. Here are my thoughts on why.

So: we usually don't think of it this way, but the Fed can be seen

simply as one of many players in the financial market. It's a very

big player, but not that big compared with the market as a whole --

the Fed has roughly $800 billion each of assets and liabilities, in

a $50 trillion credit market. And conventional monetary policy

consists, basically, of enlarging or contracting the Fed's balance

sheet. Why does the size of a financial player constituting less

than 2 percent of the credit market matter?

The answer is that the Fed's liabilities are special: nobody else

has the right to create monetary base, which can in turn be used

either as currency or as bank reserves. When the Fed expands the

money supply, the key thing isn't that it's buying Treasury bills,

it's the fact that it's doing so by expanding the monetary base,

which increases liquidity to the economy as a whole.

But in March, and again this week, interest rates on T-bills fell

close to zero -- liquidity trap territory. What does that do to the

Fed's role?

You still see people saying, in effect, "never mind the zero

interest rate, why not just print more money?" Actually, the Bank of

Japan tried that, under the name "quantitative easing;" basically,

the money just piled up in bank vaults. To see why, think of it this

way: once T-bills have a near-zero interest rate, cash becomes a

competitive store of value, even if it doesn't have any other

advantages. As a result, monetary base and T-bills -- the two sides

of the Fed's balance sheet -- become perfect substitutes. In that

case, if the Fed expands its balance sheet, it's basically taking

away with one hand what it's giving with the other: more monetary

base is out there, but less short-term debt, and since these things

are perfect substitutes, there's no market impact. That's why the

liquidity trap makes conventional monetary policy impotent.

But why not purchase stuff other than T-bills? This can be thought

of as changing the composition of the Fed's balance sheet, rather

than enlarging it; and Ben Bernanke, in happier days, thought that

might be an effective policy in a liquidity trap.

There are, however, three reasons to be doubtful about this stuff:

1. The Fed is now trying to move a much bigger rock: it is, in

effect, trying to raise the price of financial assets other than

T-bills by selling T-bills and buying other stuff. There's only

(yes, "only") $800 billion of monetary base. There are, by contrast,

many trillions of stuff other than

T-bills, so the Fed has to make huge changes in its balance sheet to

achieve any noticeable effect.

2. T-bills and other assets, such as long-term bonds, are probably

much better substitutes for each other than T-bills are for monetary

base -- money is unique as a medium of exchange, whereas once you

get past that you're only talking about competing stores of value.

So it should take much larger changes in relative supplies to get

major changes in asset prices.

3. The reason T-bills are an imperfect substitute for, say,

corporate bonds -- to the extent they are -- is risk. Therefore, the

reason changing the composition of the Fed's balance sheet can move

prices, to the extent it can, is because the Fed is taking on risk.

This isn't a role the central bank is meant to play; you're sliding

over into fiscal policy.

Nonetheless, I guess the Fed had to try the "Bernanke twist." And it

did -- the old Fed balance sheet, in which T-bills were the vast

bulk of assets, is no more. But the effects have been disappointing,

especially weighed against the risk, which I know is making Fed

officials very nervous.

And now, with the Paulson plan -- about which I have my doubts --

responsibility is clearly shifting from the Fed to the fiscal

authorities.

So Ben Bernanke came into his current position believing that

central banks have the power, all on their own, to fight Japan-type

problems. It seems that he was wrong.



More information about the lbo-talk mailing list