[lbo-talk] Cap and Trade on Carbon Omissions DOA ?

Ira Glazer ira.glazer at gmail.com
Wed Jan 21 13:12:40 PST 2009


[hat tip to yves smith at naked capitalism, http://www.nakedcapitalism.com/2009/01/is-cap-and-trade-dead-on-arrival.html#links ]

http://www.ft.com/cms/s/0/be0478b2-e692-11dd-8e4f-0000779fd2ac.html

By John Dizard

Published: January 20 2009 02:00 | Last updated: January 20 2009 02:00

Wasn't all that warm fuzziness over the election of Obama just so . . . so . . . warm and fuzzy?

Now for cold and hard-edged. That describes the emotions over intra-governmental fights that will start in earnest this week. The most immediate are over the nature of the economic stimulus, or who has the longest reach. When that is settled in the next two months, the struggle moves on to harder issues, such as reworking environmental law and regulation.

The most serious struggle will be over climate change, or the regulation of carbon emissions. You can forget all the chitchat about finding a consensus on this one: the coal people and the enviros are in this match until one side is carried out.

For now, it appears that most of the enviros working within the legislative process intend to use a cap-and-trade programme to reduce carbon emissions. That is, large carbon dioxide emitters such as coal-based utilities will be able to buy the right to produce CO 2 . Those who, one way or another, are deemed to have reduced carbon emissions can sell emission rights to other emitters. The programme would be designed so that over time the supply of carbon rights becomes tighter, the price higher and the incentive to reduce carbon emissions even greater. Climate change moderates, polar bears have more ice, and so on.

Wall Street and Chicago always like the creation of trading markets for new assets, especially if they can be inefficiently priced by the professionals. So while the coal people hate climate legislation, a lot of traders see an opportunity.

One of the problems, though, is that there are already government-created markets for sulphur dioxide and nitrogen oxide emissions, and those markets are in trouble. As I have written earlier in this space, a Federal appeals court decision on July 11 of last year appeared to kill the long-term value of credits under what was called the Clean Air Interstate Rule, a set of markets for pollution credits created by the Environmental Protection Agency. At a stroke, some tens of billions worth of rights to emit noxious gases were slashed in value by the court's ruling that the EPA had exceeded its authority.

The EPA, along with utilities and some enviros, asked the court to modify or reconsider its decision, and, unusually, the court had second thoughts. In late December, the court indefinitely stayed its cancellation of Cair, allowed the trading to remain in place, and told the EPA that it had to come up with a fix, sometime in the undefined future. That is the simple version.

So, the price of the right to emit one ton of sulphur over the next year, which had been up to $600-$800, fell back to as little as $100 after the initial decision, and has now, after the court's reconsideration, risen to $150-$200. At $600, utilities found it economic to build new pollution control systems before they were required by law, since they could sell for a lot of money the emission credits they earned. EPA people say that in the past few years, a million tons a year of sulphur dioxide emissions have been averted by Cair.

Enviros, and others with a special interest in breathing air with less sulphur or nitrogen oxides, wanted fewer permits at higher prices. Coal-based utilities wanted more time to build controls, and less stringent rules. There was general agreement, though, that the mechanism itself was effective in accelerating pollutant reduction.

Now, though, the court ruling, and the wider realisation that allowances under cap-and-trade are not really property rights, has chilled such markets. Risk management committees for corporate buyers and trading houses are likely to hesitate before buying pollution permits that could lose value.

So any new market-based emissions controls had better have more certainty than the flawed Cair. In leaving Cair in place, the court seemed to reason it would retain its effectiveness in reducing emissions over the next couple of years, but that is not the case. Instead, the EPA's pollution allowance market people believe the low prices created by the uncertainty over the future of Cair will have the perverse incentive of inducing utilities to use up existing pollution allowances by emitting more than they would have, while postponing building new controls. Or so the agency's economic models say.

The EPA might appeal to the Supreme Court, but that would be a long shot. It would be extremely difficult to fix Cair markets through new regulation, as the appeals court ordered. One possible fix would be "command-and-control", non-market-based limits on emissions. Those are within the EPA's powers, but wouldn't help as a precedent for carbon cap-and-trade. However, the prospect of unpopular rules might motivate an otherwise preoccupied Congress to come up with a legislative fix that overrides the confused ruling.

The Cair mess shows that it is easy to get market design wrong. With mortgage and derivatives markets, that costs billions. With Cair, it costs shortened lives.



More information about the lbo-talk mailing list